Scholars increasingly seek to proffer microfoundations for macro management theory, notably strategic management theory. These microfoundations naturally revolve around human resources. We argue that proper microfoundations for strategic management theory must recognize that the management of motivation is first and foremost a matter of the management of cognitions of organizational members, an insight that we found in goal-framing theory, an emerging perspective based on cognitive science, behavioral economics, and social psychology. Building on this insight, we argue that a key reason why strategic goals matter to firm performance - that is, firm-level value creation and value capture and sustained competitive heterogeneity - is that such goals influence value creation rooted in employee motivations. Unfolding this idea allows us to generate new insight in the relations between value creation, strategic leadership and strategic goals.
Discover the world's research
- 20+ million members
- 135+ million publications
- 700k+ research projects
Join for free
SYMPOSIUM
MICROFOUNDATIONS FOR STRATEGY:
A GOAL-FRAMING PERSPECTIVE ON THE DRIVERS
OF VALUE CREATION
NICOLAI J. FOSS
Copenhagen Business School and Norwegian School of Economics
SIEGWART LINDENBERG
University of Groningen and Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Economics Research
Scholars increasingly seek to proffer microfoundations for macro management theory,
notably strategic management theory. These microfoundations naturally revolve
around human resources. We argue that proper microfoundations for strategic man-
agement theory must recognize that the management of motivation is first and foremost
a matter of the management of cognitions of organizational members, an insight we
found in goal-framing theory, an emerging perspective based on cognitive science,
behavioral economics, and social psychology. Building on this insight, we argue that a
key reason why strategic goals matter to firm performance—that is, firm-level value
creation and value capture and sustained competitive heterogeneity—is that such
goals influence value creation rooted in employee motivations. Unfolding this idea
allows us to generate new insight into the relations among value creation, strategic
leadership, and strategic goals.
Strategic management is concerned with the
creation, identification, and exploitation of those
sources of competitive heterogeneity that result in
high levels of appropriable value creation. Yet
many of the causal linkages between the strategic
management process and value creation are un-
clear. In particular, how do strategic goals affect
value creation? One hypothesis is that such goals
mainly steer the cognition and actions of the top
management team. Another is that strategic goals
affect the very functioning of the firm in the sense
that they influence its internal governance and the
cognition and motivation of organizational mem-
bers, not just the top management. In this article we
make the case that strategic goals matter in this
broader sense. Understanding how this works re-
quires attention to microfoundations—specifically,
to microfoundations that highlight the (inter-
twined) motivation and cognitions of individuals
(rather than, say, routines; but see Winter, 2013).
It is increasingly recognized that the microfoun-
dations of strategic management matter greatly to
the questions that scholars in the field can raise,
address, and answer (Abell, Felin, & Foss, 2008;
Van de Ven, 2013). Much of the concern with mi-
crofoundations revolves around human resources,
often argued to be the "key ingredient to organiza-
tional success and failure" (Baron & Kreps, 1999,
p. 4). Accordingly, research highlights the cogni-
tions (Gavetti, 2005) and, more often, motivations
of those human resources (Coff, 1999; Gottschalg &
Zollo, 2007).
Along with several of the other contributors to
this symposium (in particular, Felin & Barney,
2013), we argue that strategic management theory is
in need of better microfoundations. We take it as a
given that such microfoundations must involve in-
dividuals. Indeed, while individuals have been
highlighted in recent microfoundational research
in macro management theory, mainly strategic
management, we are concerned that extant research
is dichotomized. Specifically, such research starts
either from purely cognitive foundations (Gavetti,
2005; Powell, Lovallo, & Fox, 2011, p. 1370; Teece,
娀The Academy of Management Perspectives
2013, Vol. 27, No. 2, 85–102.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amp.2012.0103
85
Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright holder's express
written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.
2007) or from purely motivational foundations
(e.g., Abell et al., 2008; Gottschalg & Zollo, 2007;
Nickerson & Zenger, 2008; Wang & Barney, 2008).
However, a crucial insight that has emerged from
cognitive (social) psychology over the past 20 years
is that cognitive and motivational processes are so
strongly intertwined that they must be considered
simultaneously and as closely interacting (Kruglan-
ski, Shah, Friedman, Fishbach, Chun, & Sleeth-
Keppler, 2002).
We argue that proper microfoundations for stra-
tegic management theory should recognize the fun-
damentally intertwined nature of cognition and
motivation: The management of motivation is first
and foremost a matter of the management of over-
arching goals that link cognition and motivation.
Building on this insight, we argue that a key reason
why strategic goals matter to firm performance—
that is, firm-level value creation and value capture
and sustained competitive heterogeneity—is that
such goals influence the overarching goals of mem-
bers of the organization and thereby the value cre-
ation rooted in employee motivations (an idea al-
ready hinted at in Barney and Griffin, 1992; Hamel
and Prahalad, 1989; Kay, 2010; and Birkinshaw,
2012). The purpose of this article is to work out the
logic of this link.
We specifically show that goal-framing theory
(Lindenberg & Foss, 2011)—an emerging perspec-
tive based on cognitive science, behavioral eco-
nomics, and social psychology (e.g., Förster, Liber-
man, & Higgins, 2005; Gollwitzer & Bargh, 1996;
Kruglanski & Köpetz, 2009)—has the unique capac-
ity to address this link (Foss, 2011). We show that
the microfoundations provided by goal-framing
theory allow us to address and answer key strategy
questions in a novel manner—in particular, how
strategic goals influence firm performance. Goal-
framing theory deals with overarching goals that
influence large clusters of subgoals. Specifically,
the theory states that the overarching goal most
conducive to value creation is one that promotes a
motivation for joint production, whereby organiza-
tional members are motivated to engage in joint
productive endeavors in which they choose their
actions regarding joint goals and exert intelligent
effort to reach joint goals (Lindenberg & Foss,
2011). However, such a normative goal frame can
easily be sidelined by other overarching goals that
are explicitly or implicitly expressed in the strate-
gic management process of the firm. The crucial
mechanism is that overarching goals of employees
are subject to a top-down contagion process by
overarching goals from top management.
The motivation that is most conducive to value
creation is not mobilized by overarching goals that
make blatant reference to the maximization of prof-
its or shareholder value, exactly—we will argue—
because such strategic goals prompt employees to
adopt goal frames that are not conducive to joint
production motivation. Rather, profit, shareholder
value, and market share must not be pursued as the
major explicit strategic goal but obliquely because
of more socially oriented goals (cf. Birkinshaw,
2012; Kay, 2010).
In sum, in building our argument about the im-
pact of the strategic management process on the
contribution of human resources to value creation,
we draw on recent developments in cognitive sci-
ence, social psychology, and behavioral economics
that "provide new opportunities for merging psy-
chology and strategy" (Powell et al., 2011, p. 1370),
going beyond the dichotomization between the cog-
nitive and the motivational dimensions in extant
microfoundational research. We develop novel im-
plications for key strategy issues from goal-framing
theory. Our theory relates to established insights
particularly in the resource-based view (Barney,
1986, 1991; Foss, 2011; Kogut & Zander, 1996), but
uniquely points to the importance of the role of
overarching goals in establishing joint production
motivation as the instrument for creating maximum
value. Relatedly, we briefly discuss the huge diffi-
culties of sustaining joint production motivation
over time, which is based on the precariousness of
the normative goal frame and its tendency to give
way to competitive goal frames, as a key reason for
the decline of competitive advantages.
PSYCHOLOGICAL FOUNDATIONS OF
STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT:
GOAL-FRAMING THEORY
Beyond Behavioral Microfoundations
Research has increasingly emphasized that
sound microfoundations are important to the de-
velopment of strategic management theory. Tradi-
tionally, the microfoundations of strategic manage-
ment theory have been located in economics (i.e.,
industrial organization, organizational economics,
and financial economics; e.g., Abell et al., 2008;
Chatain & Zemsky, 2011; Coff, 1997, 1999; Lipp-
man & Rumelt, 2003; Wang & Barney, 2008), but
there are familiar limits to the explanatory leverage
86 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
of standard economics. Thus, scholars increasingly
look for microfoundations for strategy in psychol-
ogy. For example, how the heuristics of strategic
decision making emerge from experience (Bingham
& Eisenhardt, 2011) and how firm-level identifica-
tion processes influence competitive dynamics
(Livengood & Reger, 2010) are difficult to analyze
on a deep level solely from an economics perspec-
tive (which is not to say that such insights neces-
sarily escape economic modeling, e.g., Camerer &
Lovallo, 1999).
Thus, strategic management scholars have long
made use of psychology research (Hodgkinson &
Sparrow, 2002), most notably behavioral decision
theory as embodied in Cyert and March (1963) and
reflected in the emergence of the "behavioral strat-
egy" field (Bromiley, 2005; Gavetti, Levinthal, &
Ocasio, 2007; Powell et al., 2011), as well as in
cognitive perspectives (e.g., Porac & Thomas, 1990;
Weick, 1995) and notions such as attention alloca-
tion, escalation, learning myopia, and so on
(Bromiley, 2005). And yet, the editors of a special
issue of Strategic Management Journal on the "psy-
chological foundations of strategic management"
observed that "strategic management theory lacks
adequate psychological groundings," and they con-
cluded that "until strategy theory builds stronger
foundations in psychology, it will struggle to ex-
plain the facts of firm performance" (Powell et al.,
2011, p. 1370) (see also Greve, 2013). The key prob-
lem, they argue, is inadequate paradigm develop-
ment in "behavioral strategy"—that is, the merger
of cognitive and social psychology with strategic
management theory and practice. Strikingly, how-
ever, motivational issues are not mentioned in their
overview of "behavioral strategy."
The behavioral approach to strategy has not gone
uncontested. For example, Felin and Foss (2011)
criticized its philosophical foundations, arguing
that despite the stated interest in developing a more
realistic view of decision making, the behavioral
approach derives fundamentally from behaviorist
psychology and works with the same impoverished
view of decision making. Our point of departure is
different: Behavioral strategy is not sufficient be-
cause it says too little about motivation. Specifi-
cally, behavioral theory focuses all attention on
cognitive issues, such as perception, framing, expe-
riential and vocational learning, and heuristics.
However, a key theme in psychology research over
the past two decades is that cognition and motiva-
tion are strongly intertwined—so strongly inter-
twined, in fact, that often they are not meaningfully
separable (Kruglanski, 1999).
Behavioral strategy typically emphasizes search
heuristics, attention, memory, and so on as drivers
of management decisions and firm behavior. Be-
havioral strategy's starting point in bounded ratio-
nality is entirely warranted. A fundamental charac-
teristic of cognitive processes is indeed their
selectivity: Attention is selective; memory is selec-
tive; concepts and chunks of knowledge are at any
given moment only selectively accessible. Selectiv-
ity comes about by the twin process of activating
some aspects and inhibiting others (cf. Shah, Fried-
man, & Kruglanski, 2002). This creates important
differences regarding how individuals look at a sit-
uation, the key point in behavioral strategy. How-
ever, the link between these cognitive effects and
motivational effects is brought about by overarch-
ing goals. The dynamics of overarching goals com-
bines cognitive and motivational processes in their
relation to the environment, and thus the dynamics
of these goals should be the core aspect of micro-
foundations for strategic management. Goal-fram-
ing theory specifies how these links come about.
Goal-Framing Theory
A key finding of recent social psychological re-
search is that individuals act very differently in
terms of their strategy choice (defect or cooperate)
depending on cues in the environment. For exam-
ple, the very same prisoner's dilemma can carry the
label "Community game" or "Wall Street game,"
and this cue makes a big difference for the strategy
people choose (Liberman, Samuels, & Ross, 2004;
see also Pillutla & Chen, 1999). Experimental game
theory has produced very similar findings (e.g.,
Camerer, 2003). A cogent explanation for such
strong effects of cues is that they affect the relative
weight of activated overarching goals (see Keizer,
Lindenberg, & Steg, 2008; Lindenberg, 2012), as
specified in goal-framing theory (Lindenberg,
2008). Goal-framing theory is all about the fact that
a particular overarching goal can govern large sets
of subgoals and thereby change what preferences
are salient, which even affects the kind of con-
straints that are being perceived. Let us briefly take
a closer look at how this works.
Goal-framing theory distinguishes between three
overarching goals. There is the overarching hedo-
nic goal, which expresses the desire to improve (or
preserve) the way one feels right now, related to
one's need fulfillment; there is the overarching gain
2013 87 Foss and Lindenberg
goal, which expresses the desire to improve (or
preserve) one's resources; and there is the over-
arching normative goal, which expresses the desire
to act appropriately in the service of a collective
entity, such as an organization or a group. When
one of these three goals is focal, it captures so many
of the cognitive and motivational processes that it
truly "frames" the situation. Thus, these overarch-
ing goals govern what we attend to (Posner & Pe-
tersen, 1990), what alternatives we consider, and
what knowledge we draw on (Förster et al., 2005;
Gollwitzer & Bargh, 1996; Kruglanski & Köpetz,
2009). In turn, these cognitive processes have an
impact on motivation by inhibiting other goals
(Shah et al., 2002), by influencing what we like and
dislike (Ferguson & Bargh, 2004), and by governing
the expectations about what other people will do
and the criteria that are used to judge goal realiza-
tion or failure (Carver & Scheier, 1990).
Goals need to be activated (or "focal"), notably by
situational cues, to influence behavior. A goal
frame denotes an overarching goal (together with
the integrated cognitive/motivational processes
that are driven by this goal) when it is more
strongly activated than the other two overarching
goals. For example, organizational members who
are in a gain goal frame and whose specific goal
within this frame is to improve their status in the
organization will be particularly alert to informa-
tion about opportunities for improving status. The
relevant causal knowledge they activate is what
pertains to reaching this goal; they will be oriented
toward the longer term, and are likely to focus on
behavioral alternatives that advance their status po-
sition to various degrees. Opportunities pertaining
to other high-level goals (such as "behaving appro-
priately" in the service of joint production) are
likely to be more or less ignored unless they over-
lap with opportunities for the status goal.
A goal frame does not completely inhibit the
other two overarching goals. Rather, it pushes these
other goals to the background to various degrees.
More often than not, motivations are therefore
mixed, and it depends on the relative strength of
the foreground and background goals what the final
effect will be. Cues in the environment will heavily
influence the relative weight, thereby creating
shifts in cognitions and motivations. However, due
to a different a priori strength of the overarching
goals, it takes stronger cues to increase the weight
of a normative goal frame than for the hedonic goal
frame (with the gain goal frame in between). This
makes evolutionary sense: From an evolutionary
point of view, the group is there for the adaptive
advantage of the individual and not the other way
around. Thus the goal frame pertaining to a group
orientation is a priori the weakest and thus highly
precarious. The hedonic goal frame pertaining to
the satisfaction of needs here and now is a priori
the strongest, and the goal frame pertaining to re-
sources is in between.
1
The important additional point for the micro-
foundations of strategic management is that the
most potent cues in the environment that affect the
relative strength of a goal frame are the signals of
goal frames of other people, especially of those in
higher positions (Aarts, Gollwitzer, & Hassin, 2004;
Keizer, Lindenberg, & Steg, 2008, 2011). This cre-
ates a strong top-down contagious process of goal
frames (Lindenberg & Foss, 2011) that is enhanced
by horizontal contagion because each employee's
goal frame becomes a cue that affects the others'
goal frames, creating a strong tendency for goal
frames to spread in a group. Because the normative
goal frame is highly precarious and because power
relations are highly asymmetrical (i.e., top-down),
employees watch out for signals that reveal the goal
frame of the management (Lindenberg, 2000;
Takeuchi, Chen, & Lepak, 2009). If higher-ups
clearly signal that they are in a normative goal
frame, it will greatly help to stabilize this goal
frame in subordinates (Brown, Treviño, & Harrison,
2005; Mühlau & Lindenberg, 2003). By the same
token, signals that higher-ups are not in a norma-
tive goal frame will weaken this goal frame in
subordinates.
GOAL FRAMING, JOINT PRODUCTION
MOTIVATION, AND VALUE CREATION
Joint Production Motivation
Different goal frames are associated with differ-
ent levels of value creation in firms because differ-
ent goal frames are associated with mobilizing mo-
tivation for very different goals. In particular, we
argue that the normative goal frame is associated
with the highest levels of value creation. The rea-
son is that this goal frame, and it alone, can moti-
vate organizational members to engage in truly col-
1
Note that while goals can displace each other, they
do not necessarily conflict. Different goals can be com-
patible, although only one goal can be in the cognitive
foreground. More on this can be found in Lindenberg and
Foss (2011).
88 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
laborative activities, what Lindenberg and Foss
(2011) called joint production motivation. Organi-
zational members can recognize a joint endeavor
and see themselves as part of this endeavor, each
with his or her own role and responsibilities, in-
volving a sharing of cognitions about the relevant
tasks, interdependencies, timing, and possible ob-
stacles to smooth coordination. This leads them to
exert intelligent and adaptive efforts that result in
productivity gains and innovativeness.
Why is joint production motivation so impor-
tant? In the strategy literature Lippman and Rumelt
(2003) modeled firms as bundles of complemen-
tary, cospecialized resources. They argued that
the "heart of business management and strategy
concerns the creation, evaluation, manipulation,
administration, and deployment of unpriced spe-
cialized resource combinations" (2003, p. 1083;
emphasis in original). While choosing new re-
sources and discovering novel ways of combining
resources are important avenues to superior perfor-
mance, it is a major point of our argument that at
the heart of specialized resource combinations is
the motivation of human resources in the bundle
(Baron & Kreps, 1999; Gottschalg & Zollo, 2007;
Lindenberg & Foss, 2011). Strategy thus has to fo-
cus first and foremost on this motivation for the
realization of whatever higher strategic goal is cho-
sen. We will argue that there is a special motivation
that may characterize interacting resources in a
bundle and that strategy should focus on activating
and increasing this motivation in the service of
achieving superior firm performance.
Another word for Lippman and Rumelt's re-
source bundles is "teams" (Alchian, 1984). Teams
are a basic form of human cooperation with an
impressive evolutionary past. Firms are indeed or-
ganized around teams of strongly complementary
human resources (Lepak & Snell, 1999; Lippman &
Rumelt, 2003), and several literatures in manage-
ment and economics research are taken up with
teams.
2
However, none of these literatures explic-
itly recognizes a key recent finding of evolutionary
anthropology: namely, that human beings are espe-
cially equipped with cognitive and motivational
faculties that are specifically geared to team-based
cooperation (i.e., motivation for joint production)
and that this is a special source of motivation that
created the adaptive advantages of humans cooper-
ating in groups. Joint production involves hetero-
geneous but complementary resources, a high de-
gree of task and outcome interdependence, and the
potential for super-additive outcomes (as in Al-
chian & Demsetz, 1972). According to what become
known as the "social brain hypothesis," the most
potent human brain power (the neocortex) evolved
as a "social brain" to allow human beings to realize
the adaptive advantages that stem from coopera-
tion in larger groups involving joint production
(Dunbar, 2003). The brain apparently contains a
hardwired ability to recognize a situation as one of
joint production, and to trigger motivational and
cognitive faculties that are specialized to facilitate
joint production (cf. Sebanz, Bekkering, & Knoblich,
2006).
3
Haidt (2012, Chapter 10) adopted the imagery of
a "hive switch," which refers to the activation of a
special (human) motivation that is specifically
geared to the pursuit of team or group goals. How-
ever, the hive terminology is potentially misleading
as it also implies an imagery of mindless, ant-like
individuals. Indeed, empirical research shows that
members of a team perceive the environment dif-
ferently than do those taking independent action,
and generate shared representations of actions and
tasks in terms of joint goals. They exert intelligent
effort to cognitively coordinate temporal and spa-
tial aspects of cooperation and to correctly antici-
pate goal-related actions from others (Sebanz et al.,
2006). In other words, they are willing to induce
and assist others to do their bit (Tomasello, Carpen-
ter, Call, Behne, & Moll, 2005).
In ambiguous situations, group members will not
wait to be instructed but rather will search actively
for ways to serve the group goal(s) (De Dreu,
Nijstad, & Van Knippenberg, 2008), and they are
heedful of their and others' contributions to the
2
The economics of the firm literature offers two very
different understandings of the nature of teams. One
derives from Alchian and Demsetz's (1972) basic charac-
terization of team production. The other derives from
Marschak and Radner's (1972) characterization of a team
as a group of agents with a common goal that can be
achieved only by an appropriate combination and coor-
dination of the individual activities of the group mem-
bers. Both contributions have given rise to much subse-
quent work. See Foss and Lindenberg (2012) for a more
extensive discussion.
3
Of course, the social brain is also involved in decep-
tion and in detection of deception (Epley, Caruso, &
Bazerman, 2006). Because of that, the normative goal
frame is important, not just the ability to put oneself into
the shoes of others. In fact, reactive egoism is most likely
when an individual is already in a gain goal frame.
2013 89 Foss and Lindenberg
collective goals (Weick & Rob, 1993). Given the
right social and cultural circumstances (Henrich et
al., 2001), a special kind of motivation that contains
all these ingredients is activated, namely "joint pro-
duction motivation." Because extant research on
teams does not recognize joint production motiva-
tion, it sidesteps "some of the most interesting...
questions about teams, including: What are the
sources of the economic surpluses in team produc-
tion, and how can they best be harnessed and di-
rected?" (Blair & Stout, 1999, pp. 267–268).
Value Creation From a Goal-Framing Perspective
The consideration of joint production motivation
changes the way one may look at value creation in
firms. Strategic management is conventionally
taken to be about the creation and appropriation of
value, specifically creating and appropriating more
value than the competition (i.e., superior financial
performance) on a sustained basis (Peteraf & Bar-
ney, 2003). While the yardstick for financial perfor-
mance is reasonably clear (e.g., average industry
profitability), what is the yardstick against which
we measure value creation? Strategy scholars who
have addressed this question have typically taken
an economics perspective and defined the maxi-
mum conceivable level of value creation as the
relevant yardstick. Thus, Lippman and Rumelt
(2003, p. 1082) in their focus on coalitions of re-
sources defined "strategic equilibrium as the state
in which all possible resource transfers that create
value have taken place." Foss and Foss (2005) fo-
cused on how the reduction of transaction costs
increases value creation, and argued that the rele-
vant yardstick is a state of zero transaction costs,
implying maximum value creation. Such states are
what economists call "first-best" states.
Note, however, that such efficiency yardsticks
are defined relative to given preferences. In stan-
dard microeconomics, preferences stay put: People
know exactly what they like and how much they
like it relative to other things, and the relevant
ranking does not change over time. (Or, if changes
of preferences take place, they are not caused by
economic factors.) In the world of standard micro-
economics, top management's changing strategic
goals or exercising transformational leadership
may have behavioral consequences at lower levels
of the organization (e.g., because of the informa-
tional content of such a change, e.g., Hermalin,
1998), but these behavioral consequences are not
(and cannot be) driven by preference changes of
organizational members. Accordingly, leaders can
influence the actions chosen by organizational
members—their work/leisure trade-offs, their be-
havioral persistence, their problem-solving inten-
sity, their exercise of sophisticated helping behav-
iors, and so on—only by changing their constraints.
By implication, the assumed stability of prefer-
ences represents a brake on value creation. It also
represents a constraint on what can meaningfully
be said about the impact of strategic goals on the
motivation of organizational members. The funda-
mental problem is that (given) preference is part of
a logic of trade-offs that tends to suppress or trivi-
alize the processes that lead to preference order-
ings. In contrast, goal-framing theory builds on a
logic of means-ends relationships, where changing
overarching goals implies changing entire sets of
situationally salient preferences. Preferences and
constraints thus interact. In terms of goal-framing
theory, standard microeconomics assumes that in-
dividuals are always and everywhere in the gain
goal frame. Thus, it is not just that preferences are
stable but also that they have a specific content—
that is, individuals (always and everywhere) seek
to pursue their own individual interests.
4
That in-
dividuals entertain such interests is uncontrover-
sial, and economics has made impressive headway
based on its single-minded examination of the
many ramifications of individuals pursuing their
own goals and intentions. Thus, agency theory and
mechanism design theory have yielded much im-
portant insight into how harmonizing collective
and individual goals can be (partially) brought
about by interest alignment through incentives
and/or supervision. However, such alignment usu-
ally requires very significant monitoring effort (of
input and/or output performance), and because of
the costliness of monitoring, it is inherently imper-
fect, thus severely limiting the actual alignment of
interests (Lindenberg, 2013). By contrast, because
of normative goal frames and joint production mo-
tivation, there is a different way to link the indi-
vidual employee to organizational goals: Individu-
als may also choose actions in terms of what serves
collective goals. Standard microeconomics rules
4
To be sure, (behavioral) economics is by no means
inconsistent with the notion that decisions can be driven
by self-esteem, excitement, fairness, and so on. However,
these are modeled as extra determinants of utility that are
not dependent on the context. In contrast, goal-framing
theory points out that the salience of various goals, such
as pursuing fairness, is context-dependent.
90 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
this out, because the team is only a context for the
realization of the agent's individual goals. The en-
tire process of deliberating upon and choosing ac-
tions in terms of group goals is thus ignored as a
source of value creation.
In sum, the notion of first-best value creation
imported from standard microeconomics assumes
that organizational members are always in a gain
goal frame (Foss & Lindenberg, 2012). The intro-
duction of the normative goal frame and its support
of joint production motivation change this: The
first-best in a situation where organizational mem-
bers are in a normative goal frame is different—
specifically, higher—relative to what it is when
organizational members are in a gain goal frame.
Because of the difficulty of establishing and main-
taining a normative goal frame and joint production
motivation, the additional economic surplus that is
caused by the motivational force of a collective
orientation accrues in the longer run. Interest align-
ment (with all its limitations) often seems a first-
best solution when one takes a short-term perspec-
tive. In this perspective, not just the longer-term
advantages of joint production motivation are ne-
glected, but so too are the costs of using interest
alignment (Lindenberg, 2013). What, more specifi-
cally, are the sources of this additional economic
surplus stemming from joint production motivation?
Joint production motivation has beneficial organ-
ization-level consequences that either directly or
indirectly translate into higher value creation, be-
cause they affect the tasks that organizational mem-
bers are willing to engage in, how much effort they
will put into these tasks, and how they coordinate
their actions. Empirical research links the norma-
tive goal frame to prosocial behaviors, such as
spontaneous sharing of knowledge (De Dreu et al.,
2008), which in turn may positively affect work
productivity and innovation performance (Tsai,
2001). The heedful interrelating discussed by
Weick and Rob (1993), and found to assist coordi-
nation in ambiguous situations (Weick & Rob,
1993) and to promote innovation performance
(Dougherty & Takacs, 2004), results from joint pro-
duction motivation. As the normative goal frame
implies a partial suspension of moral hazard/op-
portunism, it reduces the need for costly control
mechanisms (Podsakoff & MacKenzie, 1997).
Coordination costs are reduced because joint pro-
duction motivation implies that organizational
members generate shared representations of actions
and tasks in terms of joint goals, reducing the need
for planning and formalization. Individual efforts
are channeled toward the realization of common
goals. Because individuals who are in a normative
goal frame engage in fundamentally prosocial ac-
tivities that they do not engage in when in the gain
goal frame (and may choose higher levels of effort),
the first-best under joint production motivation is
higher than the first-best identified by standard
microeconomics. Because standard microeconom-
ics assumes that individuals are always in the gain
goal frame, it is simply too pessimistic with respect
to what can be achieved by human cooperation and
at the same time too optimistic about what can be
achieved using incentives to help align individual
and organizational goals.
5
In general, economics-
based strategic management therefore underesti-
mates the upside of what firms can do in terms of
value creation, because it neglects the normative
goal frame and joint production motivation.
This underestimation of cooperative potential is
confounded by a systematic neglect of the costs of
failures to achieve interest alignment by incentives
(in terms of indicator behavior, apathy, and sabo-
tage; see Lindenberg, 2013). This neglect derives to
a large extent from the fact that microeconomics
has no room for the workings of the hedonic goal
frame. Hedonic goals are directed at improving
how one feels at a particular moment, such as seek-
ing direct improvement in self-esteem, seeking ex-
citement, avoiding unpleasant effort, and reacting
to perceived unfairness (such as sabotage and tak-
ing revenge). The criteria for success in a hedonic
goal frame relate to improvements in the way one
feels, not the way things function. The considerable
power of this goal frame vis-Ã -vis rival goal frames
derives from its direct link to basic needs and emo-
tions (Ryan, Huta, & Deci, 2008).
An organization in which members take a myo-
pic perspective and are predominantly hedonically
5
This is seen clearly by Alchian and Woodward (1988,
p. 77), who in a review of Williamson (1985) concluded
that "it is important to recognize the forces of ethics,
etiquette, and 'proper, correct, reasonable, moral, etc.'
standards of conduct in controlling business relation-
ships." While they may have the language to describe
what is seemingly so important, they admitted that "we
don't know enough about how such 'moral' forces oper-
ate to say more than that they exist and should not be
ignored in seeking an understanding of how the eco-
nomic institutions of capitalism, or any other -ism,
evolve and operate....Whatever the emotive language,
'decent' behavior saves resources and enables greater
welfare."
2013 91 Foss and Lindenberg
oriented is not conducive to value creation (cf.
Lindenberg, 2004): Investments in human capital
are not undertaken, helping behaviors do not
thrive, and rewards that are not directly linked to
efforts may be useless. Such myopic behaviors may
arise even if incentives are geared to supporting a
gain goal frame. For example, Postrel and Rumelt
(1992) documented cases in which, even despite
high-powered incentives, firms had to resort to in-
tense monitoring to hinder the consequences of
employees adopting hedonic goal frames. For these
reasons, the hedonic goal frame is the goal frame
that is associated with the lowest level of value
creation.
Figure 1 depicts how goal frames and value cre-
ation are related (for the two kinds of human re-
sources, x
1
and x
2
, interacting in a team, but gen-
eralizable to n human resources). The key
questions raised by the figure are how firms can
reach the level of value creation associated with the
goal frame, and, once reached, how firms can main-
tain this level of value creation.
STRATEGIC CONCERNS: LINKING JOINT
PRODUCTION MOTIVATION, GOVERNANCE,
AND STRATEGIC GOALS
There are two interrelated avenues by which stra-
tegic management can affect the motivation for
joint production and thereby bring about high lev-
els of appropriable value creation. One is the direct
way: by making the internal governance structure
for joint production motivation a core concern for
strategy. The other way is indirect: adopting an
oblique approach to strategic opportunities (Birkin-
shaw, 2012; Kay, 2010)—that is opportunities that
increase appropriable value creation (Denrell,
Fang, & Winter, 2003). However, these two ap-
proaches may support each other: A governance
structure that supports joint production motivation
is positively or negatively affected by strategic
goals of the firm. Only oblique (and typically proso-
cial) strategic goals will support a governance
structure for joint production motivation. More-
over, we argue, both ways are interrelated with
leadership style, which gives leadership style a
central place in strategy (see Figure 2). In the re-
mainder of the article, we will unfold the logic that
generated Figure 2.
The Internal Governance Structure
as Strategic Concern
As stated, goal frames have a strong tendency to
spread in a group. The more employees see others
committed to joint production, the stronger their
own commitment. For example, to the degree to
which others have positive feelings about their
jobs, employees are more willing to use intelligent
effort in terms of innovativeness (Shipton, West,
Parkes, Dawson, & Patterson, 2006). Similarly, re-
ceiving positive relational signals from others in
the daily interaction on the shop floor fosters send-
ing positive relational signals and increases overall
performance (Colquitt, 2004; Tabibnia, Satpute, &
Lieberman, 2008). Conversely, colleagues who
FIGURE 1
Value Creation Frontiers and Goal Frames
X1
X2
FIGURE 2
The Key Concerns for Strategic Management
Based on Goal-Framing Theory
Transformational
leadership style
Governance
structure for
joint production
motivation
Oblique
approach to
strategic
opportunities
Joint production
motivation
High levels of
appropriable value
creation
92 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
clearly show that they work for their own goals
(gain or hedonic), rather than for company goals,
can drag many others to their side.
Colleagues have a weaker contagion effect than
higher-ups. As already mentioned, the normative
goal frame is highly precarious and power relations
are highly asymmetrical (i.e., top-down), and be-
cause of this, employees watch out for signals that
reveal the goal frame of the management (Mühlau &
Lindenberg, 2003; Takeuchi et al., 2009). If higher-
ups clearly signal that they are in a normative goal
frame, it will greatly help to stabilize this goal
frame in subordinates (Brown et al., 2005; Mühlau
& Lindenberg, 2003). By the same token, signals
that higher-ups are not in a normative goal frame
will weaken this goal frame in subordinates. For
example, in a vignette study, Keizer, Lindenberg,
and Steg (2011) showed that when higher-ups use
company money for their private purposes, em-
ployees are less inclined to keep to their own work
rules. In short, such "goal contagion" effects (Aarts
et al., 2004) can strongly influence the stability of
the normative goal frame in both positive and neg-
ative directions. This also limits the ability of man-
agement to use the language of cooperation, joint
production, and solidarity as a means to get indi-
viduals to work for company goals without believ-
ably signaling that they are in a normative goal
frame. Signaling such a normative goal frame is
inherently difficult. Because of the difference in
power and in stakes with regard to company prof-
its, employees don't easily trust higher-ups, which
makes relational signals from the top very costly
and easily distorted. Therefore, management sig-
naling of a normative goal frame needs support
from other structures (cf. also Foss, Reinholdt, Ped-
ersen, & Stea, 2013).
In previous work (Lindenberg & Foss, 2011), we
have identified the organizational preconditions
for the activation of a normative goal frame that is
conducive to joint production motivation. For rea-
sons of space, we only briefly summarize these
preconditions. First, members of an organization
must perceive their various interdependencies re-
garding joint production (through the team and task
structure). Thus, employees must understand that
tasks and teams are designed for the achievement
and maintenance of joint production. The clearer
the common goals, the various roles in which indi-
viduals help to reach these goals, and the func-
tional connections of tasks and goals between dif-
ferent levels of the firm, the easier it is for
employees to develop and sustain a motivation for
joint production. Second, even if common goals are
specified in the task and team design, they must
still be embedded in a shared sense of common
direction and affect on the level of the firm. This
will also help prevent subunit egoism. A suitable
means for achieving a common direction is a vision
and mission statement, consensually supported by
top management, that focuses on a common pur-
pose (Ashforth & Johnson, 2001) rather than oper-
ational goals that are appropriate for the task and
team structure.
Third, reward structures must be calibrated so
that they provide direct support for the normative
goal frame (i.e., individual rewards should be ex-
plicitly recognitions for contributions to joint pro-
duction, and team rewards for contributions to
high-level goals). This also holds for indirect sup-
port by keeping the gain goal frame in the back-
ground strong enough to stall excessive group pres-
sure and conformism. In addition to noncontingent
rewards linked to position, employees also need to
be rewarded individually in a contingent manner to
maintain the motivation to engage in certain activ-
ities. But contingent gain rewards, such as status
advancement and money, must remain modest, be-
cause they can foster a gain goal frame, just as
contingent hedonic rewards, such as especially en-
joyable tasks and better offices, can foster a hedonic
goal frame. When rewards get too strong, they can
undermine the normative goal frame, and intelli-
gent effort will be selectively driven by what leads
to personal rewards (hedonic or gain) rather than
by contribution to the realization of common goals.
Fourth, authority should be legitimized regarding
the functional prerequisites for joint production, by
linking it to superior insight on what is needed for
the realization of common goals, rather than based
on fiat and contractual clauses.
Gain-Related Strategic Goals and
the Importance of Obliquity
Goal-framing theory explicitly addresses high-
level (strategic) goals. But true to the importance of
motivation for joint production, it focuses on the
implications of such high-level goals for motiva-
tion. The key to understanding how this works is
the vertical contagion effect. Thus, if firms adopt
goals that stress seeking to continually seize profit
opportunities (as in Avon Products' "We will de-
liver superior returns to our shareholders by tire-
lessly pursuing new growth opportunities"), this
sends a signal down through the organization that
2013 93 Foss and Lindenberg
top management is in a gain goal frame. Due to the
contagion effect of overarching goals, this means
that the gain goal fame will spread throughout the
organization. Thus, if gains are explicitly addressed
as the key strategic goal, this makes it difficult, if
not impossible, to maintain a governance structure
that supports joint production motivation.
Therefore, goal-framing theory would maintain
that even though firms have to make profits, gain-
related strategic goals should not get center stage
(Lindenberg, 2013). They should be approached
obliquely. This point has also been picked up re-
cently by popular management books that have
made the case for "oblique" strategic goals (explic-
itly in Birkinshaw, 2012; Kay, 2010). There, the
arguments for this oblique approach remain some-
what fuzzy. As Birkinshaw (2012, p. 124) noted,
obliquity is "not an easy concept to come to grips
with," and it is not well established in the research
literature in strategic management (in fact, as far as
we can tell, there has been no attention to the
concept or the underlying ideas in the research
literature).
Scholars who have examined the impact of stra-
tegic goals on the internal workings of the firm have
provided part of the answer by emphasizing that
organizational goals serve the functions of provid-
ing direction, facilitating planning, and assisting in
the process of evaluating and controlling perfor-
mance (Barney & Griffin, 1992). The potential mo-
tivating role of strategic goals frequently emerges in
such discussions.
6
For example, Hamel and Prahal-
ad's (1989, p. 64) discussion of strategic intent
linked this construct to an "active management
process that includes focusing the organization's
attention on the essence of winning, motivating
people by communicating the value of the target,
leaving room for individual and team contributions
[and] sustaining enthusiasm by providing new op-
erational definitions as circumstances change." But
lacking microfoundations that deal with the inte-
gration of cognition and motivation through over-
arching goals, the possibility and importance of
obliquity have not been theorized. Goal-framing
theory can give a clear underpinning of the impor-
tance of obliquity with regard to gain goals, and, as
we will see shortly, some of the world's best known
corporations seem to have arrived at the same
point. Let us look at this link between strategy and
obliquity in more detail.
Strategic goals exist at different levels, from mis-
sion and vision statements at the highest strategic
level to operational goals at the business-unit level
to the goals set for individual organizational mem-
bers. In this discussion, we focus on the high-level
strategic goals that define aspirations and direc-
tions for the firm as a whole, but the arguments are
meant to apply equally to strategic goals nested in
lower levels. High-level strategic goals of the organ-
ization are the embedding for lower-level strategic
goals and thus influence the weight of goal frames
inside the firm, thereby indirectly affecting the mo-
tivation for joint production. Such goals have a
double function. Overarching goals are highly con-
tagious, especially when they are imbued with sta-
tus. Because the normative goal frame is a priori
weaker than the gain goal frame, the former will be
easily displaced by the latter. In this way high-level
goals will have a trickle effect through all levels of
the organization, if it is known that management
("status") stands behind these goals.
But high-level strategic goals also have another
important function: They help or hinder coordi-
nated action and the use and sharing of knowledge,
depending on how they affect the employees' un-
derstanding of higher-level goals. For example, in-
creasing market share as a strategic goal pushes a
gain goal frame. That alone makes it difficult to
maintain a normative goal frame for joint produc-
tion motivation. But such a goal also makes it dif-
ficult for employees to know how their tasks relate
to those of others, not giving them a sense of why
and how they matter (see Anand, Ward, Tatikonda,
& Schilling, 2009; Montgomery, 2008). This too,
frustrates the realization and maintenance of joint
production motivation.
High-level strategic goals refer either directly to
gain (profit or market share, shareholder value, etc.)
or to a substantive mission in terms of societal
goals. In both versions, these goals that define the
aspirations of firms are quite abstract and not very
operational. But they are directional, providing
purpose, and that is their strategic function, as
Montgomery pointed out: "Sitting at the hub of the
strategy wheel, purpose aligns all the functional
pieces and draws the company into a logically con-
sistent whole. Well understood, it serves as both a
constraint on activity and a guide to behavior"
(2008, p. 56).
6
There is also work on the motivational ramifications
of employee involvement in strategic planning (e.g.,
Ketokivi & Castaner, 2004), but this is distinct from our
focus here on the motivational implications of strategic
goals (i.e., outcomes of planning processes).
94 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
For example, compare the mission statement of
the Cooper Tire & Rubber Company with that of
IKEA. "The purpose of the Cooper Tire & Rubber
Company is to earn money for its shareholders and
increase the value of their investment. We will do
that through growing the company, controlling as-
sets and properly structuring the balance sheet,
thereby increasing EPS, cash flow, and return on
invested capital." This mission is clearly directed
at gain, and it will push a gain goal frame in its
employees. In addition, it does not help employees
to define their own role, to understand their pur-
pose in the organization. This contrasts with
IKEA's mission statement, which is to "offer a wide
range of home furnishing items of good design and
function, excellent quality and durability, at prices
so low that the majority of people can afford to buy
them." This mission statement can serve collective
identification with firm goals (thus supporting a
normative goal frame), and it helps the individual
employee to give direction to his or her own role in
realizing the collective goals.
Similarly, LEGO's mission is "to help children
develop their creativity and learning skills through
constructive play." This goal is both easy to iden-
tify with (thus supporting a collective orientation
to the firm's goal) and concrete enough to give each
employee a sense of what it is that needs to be done
(Lindenberg & Foss, 2011). High-level strategic
goals can also be explicitly linked to goals of the
employees. For example, the pharmaceutical com-
pany Eisai explicitly states that "it is most impor-
tant that we know and share the feelings of the
patients, their joys, anger, sadness, and happiness.
The essence of Eisai is our pursuit of the 'Eisai
way,' which is realized through the exercise of
strong entrepreneurship by each employee" (in
Spender & Strong, 2012, p. 18).
The Strategic Importance of Leadership Style
For both ways to influence the motivation for
joint production (governance structure and obliq-
uity with regard to gain goals), there is likely to be
a symbiotic relationship with leadership style,
which imbues leadership style with strategic im-
portance. First, there is the top-down contagion
process that gives considerable weight to the over-
arching goals of leaders for affecting the goal frames
of the employees. Thus, for obliquity to work, the
leadership must be seen as supporting these high-
level goals in daily practice. Second, leadership
can actively encourage identification with the or-
ganization and foster the preconditions for employ-
ees to be motivated to take individual responsibil-
ity for reaching collective goals. In the literature,
such leadership has been identified as transforma-
tional (Grant, 2012; Judge & Piccolo, 2004; Kirkpat-
rick & Locke, 1996).
Overall, this literature asserts that (strategic)
leaders motivate followers/employees by commu-
nicating compelling visions, typically in the con-
text of stressing collective identities and strongly
held core human values that can motivate followers
to switch from gain goal frames to normative goal
frames (Shamir, House, & Arthur, 1993). Thus, from
the point of view of goal-framing theory, transfor-
mational leaders need to capture motivating as-
pects of the high-level goals and use them to steer
identification processes so that they provide direct
support for the normative goal frame by embedding
common goals (Van Knippenberg, 2000) and pro-
viding links to values (Thompson & Bunderson,
2003). Because the normative goal frame is linked
to a supra-individual entity, there must be particu-
lar emphasis on what organizational members have
in common, what binds them, together with the
creation and maintenance of positive affect con-
nected to what organizational members have in
common (Bollen & Hoyle, 1990; Liberman et al.,
2004; Zaccaro & McCoy, 1988).
Grant (2012, p. 458) noted that findings in the
transformational leadership literature have been
mixed, with "inconsistent effects of transforma-
tional leadership on followers' performance"
emerging in laboratory as well as field experiments.
A possible reason is that leaders may fail to take
steps "to ensure that the vision is not simply rhet-
oric" (Kirkpatrick & Locke, 1996, p. 37). Indeed,
goal-framing theory suggests that strategic "as if "
relational campaigns that actually try only to create
the appearance of relational concern and concern
for individual improvement will not be effective for
long and will ultimately drive out normative goal
frames in favor of gain or hedonic goal frames
(Greenberg, 1990; Miller, 2001). Of course, leaders
also have a transactional role of control, but that
should be embedded in the transformational ap-
proach. This means that control too needs to be
approached obliquely.
Grant (2012) suggested that transformational
leadership is most effective with respect to moti-
vating followers when leaders lead by example and
engage in direct contact with followers. Goal-fram-
ing theory supports this idea by pointing to the
precariousness of the normative goal frame and the
2013 95 Foss and Lindenberg
fact that employees are highly sensitive to signals
that can reveal what goal frame the management is
in (Mühlau & Lindenberg, 2003; Six & Sorge, 2008;
Takeuchi et al., 2009). What Grant called "benefi-
ciary contact," for example, when leaders visibly
work with organizational members ("beneficia-
ries") in a manner oriented toward joint produc-
tion, can signal the normative goal frame of leaders
and show organizational members that strategic
goals are indeed geared toward joint production
and underpinned by prosocial visions that make a
difference to stakeholders. Because of the conta-
gion effects on the stability of the normative goal
frame, seeing that strategic leaders, in special com-
munal events, show affective and consensual com-
mitment to a cause and the related vision/mission,
and seeing that many other employees experience
this simultaneously, creates affective communality
among organizational members (see Islam & Zy-
phur, 2009; Trice & Beyer, 1984). In short, there is
need for a transactional role of control, but it is of
strategic importance that the leadership actually
"live" their strategic goals that keep gain goals
oblique.
CONCLUSIONS
From the point of view of pragmatic management
research, microfoundations matter—not so much
because microfoundations are philosophically the
right thing to do, but because they furnish substan-
tive implications for theory building that truly mat-
ter to practitioners. This insight is not new, but
until now, microfoundations for strategic manage-
ment have separated the cognitive and motiva-
tional dimensions and neglected their crucial inter-
connection in the dynamics of overarching goals.
To be sure, the investigation of the effects of heu-
ristics and biases on the behavior of top-manage-
ment teams (Powell et al., 2011) is a worthwhile
endeavor, as is the integration of motivation re-
search with strategic management (Coff, 1997; Os-
terloh & Frey, 2000). However, consistent with im-
portant recent research in experimental economics,
social psychology, and cognitive science, goal-
framing theory argues that cognitive and motiva-
tional microfoundations are strongly intertwined,
and that both dimensions should be taken into
account—and that this makes a substantive differ-
ence in theory development in strategic manage-
ment. Specifically, goal-framing theory allows us to
cast the fundamental strategic management issues
of value creation and strategic goals in a new light
and to explore their interrelations (cf. Figures 1
and 2).
On the basis of goal-framing theory one can thus
argue that the heart of value creation in firms lies in
the motivation for joint production for all involved.
No matter what the firm wants to achieve, optimal
value creation will always crucially depend on
eliciting a motivation among employees that is di-
rected at common goals, such that organizational
members are motivated to choose their actions in
terms of joint goals and exert intelligent effort to
reach joint goals (Lindenberg & Foss, 2011). Liter-
atures on human resource management (e.g., Rous-
seau & Wade-Benzoni, 1994) and goal setting (e.g.,
Locke & Latham, 2002) often address the strategic
importance of employee motivation, but they focus
not on joint production motivation but rather on
the dyadic link of the individual to the organiza-
tion. For example, Rousseau and Wade-Benzoni
(1994) argued that human resources practices are
key ways to implement strategies. Different prac-
tices implement different psychological contracts,
and the motivation of an employee is closely re-
lated to her interpretation of promises and commit-
ments issued by the organization. However, this
literature remains fundamentally dyadic in its ori-
entation; it is the relationship between the individ-
ual organizational member and the organization
that is in focus.
In traditional microeconomic approaches to
strategy, the joint production motivation has also
been neglected, as have the costs of failing to align
interests with incentives. Yet, from a strategic man-
agement point of view, it is exactly the motivation
for joint production that is crucial for optimal value
creation. Accordingly, we have argued that the core
strategic concern is to create a governance structure
that can bring about and maintain a high level of
joint production motivation among all members of
the organization. One way to do this is to make the
governance structure itself a key strategic concern
(for more detail, see Lindenberg & Foss, 2011).
For the strategy field, another influence on the
motivation for joint production is possibly less ob-
vious but just as important: the influence of high-
level strategic goals on motivation. Because of their
obvious centrality, high-level strategic goals have
been extensively discussed from multiple perspec-
tives. For example, agency theorists have discussed
the extent to which the goals of the firm are aligned
with those of shareholders (Jensen & Meckling,
1976), resource-based theorists see the goals of the
96 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
firm as constrained by the resource portfolio of the
firm (Wernerfelt, 1984), positioning theory ex-
plains how goals are constrained by external com-
petitive forces (Porter, 1980), competitive dynam-
ics theory emphasizes how environmental changes
influence changes in strategic goals (Audia, Locke,
& Smith, 2000), strategy process theories explain
how goals may emerge from lower echelons in the
organization (Burgelman, 1994) or reflect changing
levels of aspiration (Shinkle, 2012) or reference
points (Fiegenbaum, Hart, & Schendel, 1996,
p. 222), and strategic leadership theorists examine
how goals are influenced by the discretion pos-
sessed by strategic managers (Finkelstein & Ham-
brick, 1996). However, whether, how, and why
strategic goals have to deal with obliquity is gener-
ally not addressed in the strategic management
literature.
As has become clear from the point of view of
goal-framing theory, with regard to high-level stra-
tegic goals, strategic management involves a funda-
mental squaring-of-the-circle operation: On one
hand the overall aim is indeed to maximize appro-
priable value creation relative to the competition.
This seems to require a competitive and economiz-
ing mindset associated with the gain goal frame. By
contrast, because of promoting such a mindset in-
ternally (via the operation of the vertical goal con-
tagion mechanism), organizational members adopt
the gain goal frame, which is associated with a
lower level of value creation than the normative
goal frame. This implies that the successful maxi-
mization of net returns requires an oblique strate-
gy—that is, one that stresses explicit goals that can
support the normative goal frame, which in turn is
conducive to joint production motivation and aids
a governance structure that is supportive of joint
product motivation.
A good example of a successful oblique approach
is the Swedish bank Svenska Handelsbanken. Kro-
ner (2011) showed that the bank's strategic goal of
higher return on equity than the average of its peers
is pursued in a rather oblique way and is supported
by an internal organization that is conducive to
joint production. Thus, Handelsbanken's culture
stresses employees being "self-directed and entre-
preneurial" (p. 93) with a high degree of account-
ability; the task structure is simple and highly
transparent (p. 96), and "Handelsbanken does not
award bonuses" (p. 98). This internal organization
supports the "bank's visceral dislike for risk-taking,
its focus on concentrating on customer satisfaction
over profits, and its emphasis on long-term orien-
tation" (p. 99). Svenska Handelsbanken has been
consistently successful in pursuing its strategic
goal in this oblique way, placing it among the top
25 banks in Europe.
This success of Handelsbanken is a testament to
yet another strategic concern derivable from goal-
framing theory: the importance of transformational
leadership. Such leadership is important in making
strategic gain goals oblique, in creating common
purpose, and in maintaining a governance structure
that is supportive of joint production motivation.
The three strategic concerns suggested here (gover-
nance, oblique gain goals, and transformational
leadership) take time and a long-term perspective
to develop and might well constitute the heart of
the complex and path-dependent resources high-
lighted by the resource-based perspective (Bar-
ney, 1991).
REFERENCES
Aarts, H., Gollwitzer, P. M., & Hassin, R. R. (2004). Goal
contagion: Perceiving is for pursuing. Journal of Per-
sonality and Social Psychology, 87(1), 23–37.
Abell, P., Felin, T., & Foss, N. J. (2008). Building micro-
foundations for the routines, capabilities and perfor-
mance link. Managerial and Decision Economics, 29,
489–502.
Alchian, A. A. (1984). Specificity, specialization, and
coalitions. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Economics, 140, 34–49.
Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, infor-
mation costs, and economic organization. American
Economic Review, 62, 772–795.
Alchian, A. A., & Woodward, S. (1988). The firm is dead;
long live the firm. A review of Oliver E. Williamson's
The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Journal of
Economic Literature, XXVI, 65–79.
Anand, G., Ward, P. T., Tatikonda, M. V., & Schilling,
D. A. (2009). Dynamic capabilities through continu-
ous improvement infrastructure. Journal of Opera-
tions Management, 27, 444–461.
Ashforth, B. E., & Johnson, S. A. (2001). Which hat to
wear? The relative salience of multiple identities in
organizational contexts. In M. A. Hogg & D. J. Terry
(Eds.), Social identity processes in organizational
contexts (pp. 31–48). Philadelphia: Psychology Press.
Audia, P. G., Locke, E. A., & Smith, K. G. (2000). The
paradox of success: An archival and a laboratory
2013 97 Foss and Lindenberg
study of strategic persistence following radical envi-
ronmental change. Academy of Management Jour-
nal, 43(5), 837–853.
Barney, J. B. (1986). Organizational culture: Can it be a
source of sustained competitive advantage? Acad-
emy of Management Review, 11, 656–665.
Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained com-
petitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17 ,99–
120.
Barney, J. B., & Griffin, R. W. (1992). The management of
organizations: Strategy, structure, behavior. Boston:
Houghton Mifflin.
Baron, J. N., & Kreps, D. M. (1999). Strategic human
resources: Frameworks for general managers. New
York: Wiley.
Bingham, C. B., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2011). Rational
heuristics: The "simple rules" that strategists learn
from process experience. Strategic Management
Journal, 32, 1437–1464.
Birkinshaw, J. (2012). Reinventing management: Smarter
choices for getting work done. New York: Wiley.
Blair, M. M., & Stout, L. (1999). A team production theory
of corporate law. Virginia Law Review, 85(2), 247–
328.
Bollen, K. A., & Hoyle, R. H. (1990). Perceived cohesion:
A conceptual and empirical examination. Social
Forces, 69, 479–504.
Bromiley, P. (2005). The behavioral foundations of stra-
tegic management. Oxford, UK: Blackwell.
Brown, M. E., Treviño, L. K., & Harrison, D. A. (2005).
Ethical leadership: A social learning perspective for
construct development and testing. Organizational
Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 97, 117–
134.
Burgelman, R. A. (1994). Fading memories: A process
theory of strategic business exit in dynamic environ-
ments. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39, 24–56.
Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experi-
ments on strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Prince-
ton University Press.
Camerer, C. F., & Lovallo, D. (1999). Overconfidence and
excess entry: An experimental approach. American
Economic Review, 89, 306–318.
Carver, C. S., & Scheier, M. F. (1990). Principles of self-
regulation. Action and emotion. In E. T. Higgins &
R. M. Sorrentino (Eds.), Handbook of motivation and
cognition (Foundations of social behavior), vol. 2.
New York: Guilford Press.
Chatain, O., & Zemsky, P. (2011). Value creation and
value capture with frictions. Strategic Management
Journal, 32, 1206–1231.
Coff, R. W. (1997). Human assets and management dilem-
mas: Coping with hazards on the road to resource-
based theory. Academy of Management Review, 22,
374–402.
Coff, R. (1999). When competitive advantage doesn't lead
to performance: Resource-based theory and stake-
holder bargaining power. Organization Science, 10,
119–133.
Colquitt, J. A. (2004). Does the justice of the one interact
with the justice of the many? Reactions to procedural
justice in teams. Journal of Applied Psychology,
89(4), 633–646.
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of
the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
De Dreu, C. K., Nijstad, B. A., & Van Knippenberg, D.
(2008). Motivated information processing in group
judgment and decision making. Personality and So-
cial Psychology Review, 12(1), 22–49.
Denrell, J., Fang, C., & Winter, S. G. (2003). The econom-
ics of strategic opportunity. Strategic Management
Journal, 24, 977–990.
Dougherty, D., & Takacs, H. (2004). Team play: Heedful
interrelating as the boundary for innovation. Long
Range Planning, 37, 569–590.
Dunbar, R. I. M. (2003). The social brain: Mind, language,
and society in evolutionary perspective. Annual Re-
view of Psychology, 32, 163–181.
Epley, N., Caruso, E., & Bazerman, M. H. (2006). When
perspective taking increases taking: Reactive egoism
in social interaction. Journal of Personality and So-
cial Psychology, 91(5), 872–889.
Felin, T., & Barney, J. B. (2013). Microfoundations of
organization and strategy: Half-truths, truths, and
future directions. Academy of Management Perspec-
tives, 27(2).
Felin, T., & Foss, N. J. (2011). The endogenous origins of
experience, routines and organizational capabilities:
The poverty of stimulus. Journal of Institutional Eco-
nomics, 7, 231–256.
Ferguson, M. J., & Bargh, J. A. (2004). Liking is for doing:
The effects of goal pursuit on automatic evaluation.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(5),
557–572.
Fiegenbaum, A., Hart, S., & Schendel, D. (1996). Strategic
reference point theory. Strategic Management Jour-
nal, 17, 219–235.
98 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
Finkelstein, S., & Hambrick, D. C. (1996). Strategic lead-
ership: Top executives and their effects on organiza-
tions. New York: West Publishing Company.
Förster, J., Liberman, N., & Higgins, E. T. (2005). Acces-
sibility from active and fulfilled goals. Journal of
Experimental Social Psychology, 41, 220–239.
Foss, K., & Foss, N. J. (2005). Value and transaction costs:
How the economics of property rights furthers the
RBV. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 541–553.
Foss, N. (2011). Micro-foundations for resource-based
theory. Journal of Management, 37, 1413–1428.
Foss, N. J., & Lindenberg, S. (2012). Teams, team motiva-
tion, and the theory of the firm. Managerial and
Decision Economics, 33, 363–389.
Foss, N. J., Reinholdt, M., Pedersen, T., & Stea, D. (2013).
Motivating to be prosocial: How complementary mo-
tivators reduce the ambiguity of informal rewards
(Working Paper). Copenhagen: Department of Strate-
gic Management and Globalization, Copenhagen
Business School.
Gavetti, G. (2005). Cognition and hierarchy: Rethinking
the microfoundations of capabilities' development.
Organization Science, 16, 599–617.
Gavetti, G., Levinthal, D., & Ocasio, W. (2007). Neo-Car-
negie School's past, present, and reconstructing for
the future. Organization Science, 18(3), 523–536.
Gollwitzer, P. M., & Bargh, J. A. (Eds.). (1996). The psy-
chology of action: Linking cognition and motivation
to behavior. New York: Guilford Press.
Gottschalg, O., & Zollo, M. (2007). Interest alignment and
competitive advantage. Academy of Management
Review, 32, 418–437.
Grant, A. M. (2012). Leading with meaning: Beneficiary
contact, prosocial impact, and the performance ef-
fects of transformational leadership. Academy of
Management Journal, 5, 458–476.
Greenberg, J. (1990). Organizational justice: Yesterday,
today and tomorrow. Journal of Management, 16,
399–432.
Greve, H. (2013). Microfoundations of management: Be-
havioral strategies and levels of rationality in organ-
izational action. Academy of Management Perspec-
tives, 27(2).
Haidt, J. (2012). The righteous mind. London: Allen Lane.
Hamel, G., & Prahalad, C. K. (1989). Strategic intent.
Harvard Business Review, 67, 63–76.
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E.,
Gintis, H., & McElreath, R. (2001). Cooperation, rec-
iprocity and punishment in fifteen small-scale soci-
eties. American Economic Review, 91, 73–78.
Hermalin, B. E. (1998). Toward an economic theory of
leadership: Leading by example. American Eco-
nomic Review, 88(5), 1188–1206.
Hodgkinson, G., & Sparrow, P. R. (2002). The competent
organization: A psychological analysis of the strate-
gic management process. Buckingham, UK: Open
University Press.
Islam, G., & Zyphur, M. J. (2009). Rituals in organiza-
tions: A review and expansion of current theory.
Group and Organization Management, 34, 114–139.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the
firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and own-
ership structure. Journal of Financial Economics,
3(4), 305–360.
Judge, T. A., & Piccolo, R. F. (2004). Transformational
and transactional leadership: A meta-analytic test of
their relative validity. Journal of Applied Psychol-
ogy, 89(5), 755–768.
Kay, J. (2010). Obliquity: Why our goals are best achieved
indirectly. London: Profile Books.
Keizer, K., Lindenberg, S., & Steg, L. (2008). The spread-
ing of disorder. Science, 322(5908), 1681–1685.
Keizer, K., Lindenberg, S., & Steg, L. (2011). Higher-ups
make especially influential norm violators (Working
Paper). The Netherlands: University of Groningen.
Ketokivi, M., & Castañer, X. (2004). Strategic planning as
an integrative device. Administrative Science Quar-
terly, 49(3), 337–365.
Kirkpatrick, S. A., & Locke, E. A. (1996). Direct and
indirect effects of three core charismatic leadership
components on performance and attitudes. Journal
of Applied Psychology, 81, 36–51.
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. (1996). What firms do? Coordi-
nation, identity, and learning. Organization Science,
7, 502–517.
Kroner, N. (2011). A blueprint for better banking. Hamp-
shire, UK: Harriman House.
Kruglanski, A. (1999). Motivation, cognition, and reality:
Three memos for the next generation of research.
Psychological Inquiry, 10(1), 54–58.
Kruglanski, A. W., & Köpetz, C. (2009). What is so special
(and non-special) about goals? A view from the cog-
nitive perspective. In G. B. Moskowitz & H. Grant
(Eds.), The psychology of goals (pp. 27–55). New
York: Guilford Press.
Kruglanski, A. W., Shah, J. Y., Friedman, R., Fishbach,
A., Chun, W. Y., & Sleeth-Keppler, D. (2002). A the-
2013 99 Foss and Lindenberg
ory of goal systems. Advances in Experimental So-
cial Psychology, 34, 331–378.
Lepak, D. P., & Snell, S. A. (1999). The human resource
architecture: Toward a theory of human capital allo-
cation and development. Academy of Management
Review, 24, 31–48.
Liberman, V., Samuels, S. M., & Ross, L. (2004). The
name of the game: Predictive power of reputations
versus situational labels in determining prisoner's
dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psy-
chology Bulletin, 30(9), 1175–1185.
Lindenberg, S. (2000). It takes both trust and lack of
mistrust: The workings of cooperation and relational
signaling in contractual relationships. Journal of
Management and Governance, 4, 11–33.
Lindenberg, S. (2003). The cognitive side of governance.
Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 20, 47–
76.
Lindenberg, S. (2004). Myopia's price: Inefficiencies in
organizations. In A. Diekmann & T. Voss (Eds.), Ra-
tional-choice-Theorie in den Sozialwissenschaften
(pp. 217–229). Munich: Oldenbourg.
Lindenberg, S. (2006). Prosocial behavior, solidarity, and
framing processes. In D. Fetchenhauer, A. Flache,
A. P. Buunk, & S. Lindenberg (Eds.), Solidarity and
prosocial behavior: An integration of sociological
and psychological perspectives (pp. 23–44). New
York: Springer.
Lindenberg, S. (2008). Social rationality, semi-modular-
ity and goal-framing: What is it all about? Analyse
und Kritik, 30, 669–687.
Lindenberg, S. (2012). How cues in the environment
affect normative behavior. In L. Steg, A. E. van den
Berg, & J. I. M. de Groot (Eds.), Environmental psy-
chology: An introduction. New York: Wiley.
Lindenberg, S. (2013). Cognition and governance: Why
incentives have to take the back seat. In A. Grandori
(Ed.), Handbook of economic organization. London:
Elgar.
Lindenberg, S., & Foss, N. J. (2011). Managing joint pro-
duction motivation: The role of goal framing and
governance mechanisms. Academy of Management
Review, 36(3), 500–525.
Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. (2003). A bargaining
perspective on resource advantage. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 24, 1069–1086.
Livengood, R. S., & Reger, R. K. (2010). That's our turf!
Identity domains and competitive dynamics. Acad-
emy of Management Review, 35, 48–66.
Locke, E. A., & Latham, G. P. (2002). Building a practi-
cally useful theory of goal setting and task motiva-
tion: A 35-year odyssey. American Psychologist,
57(9), 705–717.
Marschak, J., & Radner, R. (1972). Economic theory of
teams. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Metcalfe, J., & Mischel, W. (1999). A hot/cool-system
analysis of delay of gratification: Dynamics of will-
power. Psychological Review, 106(1), 3–19.
Miller, D. T. (2001). Disrespect and the experience of
injustice. Annual Review of Psychology, 52, 527–
553.
Montgomery, C. A. (2008). Putting leadership back into
strategy. Harvard Business Review, 86(1), 54–60.
Mühlau, P., & Lindenberg, S. (2003). Efficiency wages:
Signals or incentives? Journal of Management and
Governance, 7(4), 385–400.
Nickerson, J., & Zenger, T. (2008). Envy, comparison
costs, and the economic theory of the firm. Strategic
Management Journal, 29, 1429–1449.
Osterloh, M., & Frey, B. (2000). Motivation, knowledge
transfer and organizational form. Organization Sci-
ence, 11, 538–550.
Peteraf, M. A., & Barney, J. B. (2003). Unraveling the
resource-based tangle. Managerial and Decision Eco-
nomics, 24(4), 309–323.
Pillutla, M. M., & Chen, X. P. (1999). Social norms and
cooperation in social dilemmas: The effects of con-
text and feedback. Organizational Behavior and Hu-
man Decision Processes, 78(2), 81–103.
Podsakoff, P. M., & MacKenzie, S. B. (1997). Impact of
organizational citizenship behavior on organiza-
tional performance: A review and suggestions for
future research. Human Performance, 10, 133–151.
Porac, J. F., & Thomas, H. (1990). Taxonomic mental
models in competitor definition. Academy of Man-
agement Review, 15(2), 224–240.
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York:
Free Press.
Posner, M. I., & Petersen, S. E. (1990). The attention
system of the human brain. Annual Review of Neu-
roscience, 13, 25–42.
Postrel, S., & Rumelt, R. P. (1992). Incentives, routines,
and self-command. Industrial and Corporate
Change, 1, 397–425.
Powell, T. C., Lovallo, D., & Fox, C. (2011). Behavioral
strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 32, 1369–
1386.
100 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
Rousseau, D. M., & Wade-Benzoni, K. A. (1994). Linking
strategy and human resource practices: How em-
ployee and customer contracts are created. Human
Resource Management, 33, 463–489.
Ryan, R. M., Huta, V., & Deci, E. L. (2008). Living well: A
self-determination theory perspective on eudaimo-
nia. Journal of Happiness Studies, 9, 139–170.
Sebanz, N., Bekkering, H., & Knoblich, G. (2006). Joint
action: Bodies and minds moving together. Trends in
Cognitive Sciences, 10(2), 70–76.
Shah, J. Y., Friedman, R., & Kruglanski, A. W. (2002).
Forgetting all else: On the antecedents and conse-
quences of goal shielding. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 83(6), 1261–1280.
Shamir, B., House, R. J., & Arthur, M. B. (1993). The
motivational effects of charismatic leadership: A
self-concept based theory. Organization Science, 4,
577–594.
Shinkle, G. A. (2012). Organizational aspirations, refer-
ence points, and goals: Building on the past and
aiming for the future. Journal of Management, 38(1),
415–455.
Shipton, H. J., West, M. A., Parkes, C. L., Dawson, J. F., &
Patterson, M. G. (2006). When promoting positive
feelings pays: Aggregate job satisfaction, work design
features, and innovation in manufacturing organiza-
tions. European Journal of Work and Organizational
Psychology, 15, 404–430.
Six, F., & Sorge, A. (2008). Creating a high-trust organi-
zation: An exploration into organizational policies
that stimulate interpersonal trust building. Journal
of Management Studies, 45, 857–884.
Spender, J. C., & Strong, B. (2012). Strategic conversa-
tions. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Tabibnia, G., Satpute, A. B., & Lieberman, M. D. (2008).
The sunny side of fairness: Preference for fairness
activates reward circuitry (and disregarding unfair-
ness activates self-control circuitry). Psychological
Science, 19(4), 339–347.
Takeuchi, R., Chen, G., & Lepak, D. (2009). Through the
looking glass of a social system: Cross-level effects of
high-performance work systems on employees' atti-
tudes. Personnel Psychology, 62, 1–29.
Teece, D. J. (2007). Explicating dynamic capabilities: The
nature and micro-foundations of (sustainable) enter-
prise performance. Strategic Management Journal,
28, 1319–1350.
Thompson, J. A., & Bunderson, J. S. (2003). Violation of
principle: Ideological currency in the psychological
contract. Academy of Management Review, 28, 571–
586.
Tomasello, M., Carpenter, M., Call, J., Behne, T., & Moll,
H. (2005). Understanding and sharing intentions:
The origins of cultural cognition. Behavioral and
Brain Sciences, 28(5), 675–735.
Trice, H. M., & Beyer, J. M. (1984). Studying organiza-
tional cultures through rites and ceremonials. Acad-
emy of Management Review, 9, 653–669.
Tsai, W. (2001). Knowledge transfer in intraorganiza-
tional networks: Effects of network position and ab-
sorptive capacity on business unit innovation and
performance. Academy of Management Journal, 44,
996–1004.
Van de Ven, A. (2013). Rational and reasonable micro-
foundations of markets and institutions. Academy of
Management Perspectives, 27(2).
Van Knippenberg, D. (2000). Work motivation and per-
formance: A social identity perspective. Applied
Psychology: An International Review, 49, 357–371.
Wang, H., & Barney, J. (2008). Employee incentives to
make firm-specific investments: Implications for re-
source-based theories of corporate diversification.
Academy of Management Review, 31, 466–476.
Weick, K. E. (1995). Sense making in organizations.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Weick, K. E., & Rob, K. H. (1993). Collective mind in
organizations: Heedful interrelating on flight decks.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 38, 357–381.
Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm.
Strategic Management Journal, 5, 171–180.
Winter, S. (2013). Habit, deliberation and action:
Strengthening the microfoundations of routines and
capabilities. Academy of Management Perspectives,
27(2).
Zaccaro, S. J., & McCoy, M. C. (1988). The effects of task
and interpersonal cohesiveness on performance of a
disjunctive group task. Journal of Applied Social
Psychology, 18, 837–851.
Nicolai J. Foss (Njf.smg@cbs.dk) is Professor of Strategy
and Organization at the Copenhagen Business School
(CBS), Department Head, Department of Strategic Man-
agement and Globalization at CBS, and Professor of
Knowledge-based Value Creation at The Norwegian
School of Economics. He is a member of the Academia
Europaea, and received his Ph.D. from CBS. His interests
lie in the theoretical and empirical aspects of microfoun-
dations for strategic management theory, and in the in-
tersection of organizational economics and strategic
management.
2013 101 Foss and Lindenberg
Siegwart Lindenberg (s.m.lindenberg@rug.nl) is Profes-
sor of Cognitive Sociology in the Department of Sociol-
ogy and the Interuniversity Center for Social Science
Theory and Methodology (ICS) at the University of Gro-
ningen and at the Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Eco-
nomics Research (TIBER) at Tilburg University (Nether-
lands). He received his Ph.D. from Harvard University,
and is a member of the Royal Netherlands Academy of
Arts and Sciences. His interests lie in the development,
test, and application of theories of joint production and
governance based on social rationality, with a focus on
the influence of the social environment on norms, (non)co-
operative behavior, and self-regulation.
102 May The Academy of Management Perspectives
CopyrightofAcademyofManagementPerspectivesisthepropertyofAcademyof
Managementanditscontentmaynotbecopiedoremailedtomultiplesitesorpostedtoa
listservwithoutthecopyrightholder'sexpresswrittenpermission.However,usersmayprint,
download,oremailarticlesforindividualuse.
... Transformational leadership has become one of the most established theories of leadership in the current literature (Dinh et al., 2014). It has been considered one of the most performance influencing leadership styles (Foss and Lindenberg, 2013;Judge and Piccol, 2004) and an important factor of organizational change adaptation (Moorman and Day, 2016;Sirmon et al., 2007;Teece, 2007). Through transformational leadership, leaders motivate their subordinates to identify with the goals and interests of the firm and encourage them to perform beyond expectations (Pieterse et al., 2009). ...
... From this perspective, transformational leadership is considered pivotal in raising contextual ambidexterity (Floyd and Lane, 2000;Gibson and EJIM . Transformational leaders encourage proactive exploration and exploitation of new ideas (Foss and Lindenberg, 2013). Consequently, transformational leadership firms effectively detect shifts in market trends and customers' preferences and respond to the changes through mobilizing resources according to opportunities identified through adaptive marketing capability (Day, 2011;Teece, 2007). ...
... It consequently promotes an open, creative and experimentations-based climate for exploiting and exploring market knowledge acquired through adaptive marketing capability (Mu et al., 2018;Teece, 2007). Thus, transformational leadership provides a supportive culture for proactively gathering, distributing and responding to market information (Foss and Lindenberg, 2013;Judge and Piccol, 2004), facilitates and motivates employees and fosters the organizational context to simultaneously exploit and explore new opportunities Raisch and Birkinshaw, 2008) identified through adaptive marketing capability (Day, 2011;Mu et al., 2018;Teece, 2007). ...
Purpose – This study aims to offer and validate an integrated marketing capability-product innovations framework. Particularly, it aims to examine the role of adaptive marketing capability in enabling market ambidexterity and incremental as well as radical product innovation. Also it intends to investigate the moderating role of transformational leadership between adaptive marketing capability and market ambidexterity. Design/methodology/approach – Manufacturing firms in Pakistan, an emerging economy, are taken as the context for this study. A designed survey questionnaire is used for data collection. Partial least square technique is employed to empirically validate and test the hypothesized model with a sample of 192 manufacturing firms. Particularly, the two-stage approach in SmartPLS is used to validate measurement models, and structural equation modeling technique is used to test the proposed hypothesis. Findings – The findings not only confirm that adaptive marketing capability is instrumental to both incremental and radical product innovations but also reveal that adaptive marketing capability serves an important antecedent to market ambidexterity shedding new lights on its mediating role in the relationship of adaptive marketing capability with incremental and radical product innovations. Moreover, the results find that the effectiveness of adaptive marketing capability to support market ambidexterity may involve a possible trade-off between exploitation and exploration when the leaders exhibit a low or high level of transformational leadership behavior. Originality/value – This study contributes to outside-in strategic perspective and contextual ambidexterity literature by revealing the role of adaptive marketing capability as an important enabler of market ambidexterity which, in turn, allows the firm to simultaneously introduce incremental and radical product innovations. In this way, this study advances the current understanding of the antecedents and consequences of contextual ambidexterity. Also, this study provides insight into the types of capabilities needed for the firm's contextual and employees' behavioral adaptation to simultaneously manage exploitation and exploration within the same business unit which was lacking in the previous literature. Further, this study also offers a novel understanding of the conditional role of transformational leadership between adaptive marketing capability and market ambidexterity.
... Within an organizational context, the strategic goals and corresponding management practices of a firm are important factors that shape the overarching goals of employees (Foss & Lindenberg, 2013;Lindenberg & Foss, 2011). ...
... As employees' goal, frames at work are subject to a contagion process by the strategic goals and management practices of the employing organization (Foss & Lindenberg, 2013), it can be assumed that EMP affects employees' EA (Pellegrini, Rizzi, & Frey, 2018). The congruence between employees' EA and a commitment to environmental protection by the employing organization in turn predicts the green-person-organization fit (Hicklenton et al., 2019). ...
... The present study contributes to this debate by highlighting beneficial employee-level reactions to EMP. The current results support the proposition that organizational practices interact with the normative goals and beliefs of employees (Aguilera, Rupp, Williams, & Ganapathi, 2007;Foss & Lindenberg, 2013) and the empirical verification of the mediating role of employees' EA has shed light on a thus far overlooked mechanism across different levels of analysis. ...
- Hans Jaich
The fundamental research question in the present study is whether perceived environmental management practices relate to employees' organizational identification. Specifically, it is hypothesized that this relationship is mediated by employees' environmental attitudes. The corresponding research model adopts a multi‐theoretical approach that combines two different theoretical lenses. Goal‐framing theory is introduced to predict whether perceived environmental management practices affect employees' environmental attitudes, while green‐person‐organization fit is applied to explain the relationship between employees' environmental attitudes and organizational identification. The research model was tested using a cross‐sectional research design with data from 206 employees from tourist service companies in Germany. The results, which largely support the research model, shed light on a thus far unexplored mechanism that mediates individual reactions to organizational practices and contrasts the more established proposition that employees first identify with their organization before they develop attitudes that are in accordance with corresponding ingroup norms. Implications for both research and practice are discussed.
... The goals set by the managers with the forethought capability function as the joint production motivation, improve the organizational performance (Lindenberg & Foss, 2011) and serve as the guidelines for value-creation (Foss & Lindenberg, 2013). The goals set by the firms about the future have positive effects on the psychology of firm managers (Locke & Latham, 1990b). ...
... The effects of self-efficacy capability on organizational operation, decision making process and organizational performance were examined in previous studies (Bandura, 1988a;Wood & Bandura, 1989a;1989b). Moreover, in previous studies, the phenomena of goal-setting and motivation which were among the sub-functions of selfefficacy capability were addressed within the context of microfoundations of strategic management (Lindenberg & Foss, 2011;Foss & Lindenberg, 2013). However, in these studies, the phenomena of goal-setting and motivation were not evaluated within the context of Social Cognitive Theory, rather in the framework of Goal-framing Theory. ...
- Mehmet Bagis
The aim of this study is to address the following question: "How does Social Cognitive Theory contribute to the microfoundations of dynamic capabilities?" Benefiting from the concepts of Social Cognitive Theory, namely, symbolizing capability, forethought capability, vicarious learning capability, self-regulatory capability and self-reflective capability, the study suggested a conceptual model for the microfoundations of dynamic capabilities. Thus, it was put forward that the managers and employees with self-capabilities had effect on the collective organizational capabilities of the firm. Moreover, it was deduced that the individual capabilities which Social Cognitive Theory set forth in relation to human nature would suggest explanations on the building (learning), coordination (integration) and reconfiguration (transformation) phenomena of dynamic capabilities.
... threat and opportunity from a new resource combination) or opposing tasks and logics of resource deployment (Eggers and Kaplan 2013;Jay 2013). The benefit is a wider range of alternative ways of recombining resources, which is central to coordination flexibility (Foss and Lindenberg 2013). Moreover, duality-accepting the tension in or challenges of resource combination-enables managers to think about what rules to break (Kaplan and Vakili 2015) and thus constitutes coordination flexibility. ...
... Second, coordination flexibility requires novel linkages between resources (Evans and Davis 2005). Holism becomes particularly helpful because a firm is encouraged to develop multiple ways of deploying and reconfiguring resources or eliminating bottlenecks in resource recombination (Uhlenbruck et al. 2003); the firm can also discover the interdependency of and acknowledge the complex interplay between irrelevant resources (Foss and Lindenberg 2013). Third, dynamism allows senior managers to understand how to modify important aspects of reconfiguring and orchestrating resources at different times (i.e. ...
- Feifei Jiang
- Donghan Wang
- Zelong Wei
This study examines the underlying mechanisms through which Yin-Yang cognition, an Eastern philosophy of paradoxical cognition, affects firm ambidexterity. Based on strategic cognition theory, this research identifies strategic flexibility as a mediator. Moreover, we also identify three fundamental characteristics of Yin-Yang cognition based on an Eastern philosophy. Using a sample of 206 manufacturing firms in China to test our model, we find that two types of strategic flexibility (resource flexibility and coordination flexibility) are important channels through which Yin-Yang cognition influences organizational ambidexterity. We describe how these findings offer several theoretical and managerial implications.
... The understanding of motivation, cognitive limitations, opportunism and incentives for generating the knowledge spillovers (West and Bogers, 2017) on individuals' openness remains scarcely investigated by scholars Randhawa et al., 2019;Salter et al., 2015;West and Bogers, 2017). Moreover, previous literature underlines the importance of the processes and structures that shape OI routines and capabilities (Bogers et al., 2018;Felin et al., 2012;Foss and Lindenberg, 2013). For example, Randhawa et al. (2019) found that the quality of an OI capability is dependent on the efficacy of supervisory-level managers. ...
Purpose In this paper, the authors argue that multicultural skills and relational leadership act as enablers for open innovation, and thereby examine the process through which teams can utilize multicultural skills to support the development of relational leadership and knowledge sourcing and sharing (KSS) through individual interaction and relationship building. The authors address the following research question: How does relational leadership enable open innovation (OI) among employees with multicultural skills? Design/methodology/approach This paper applies a multi-level approach (team and individual level) and builds on interviews with 20 employees, middle and senior managers with multicultural experiences, working in open innovation environments. Findings The authors' findings shed light on the process through which social exchange relationships among team members (e.g. R&D teams) and knowledge exchange partners are enhanced by the use of multicultural skills and support the development of relational leadership to facilitate KSS and ultimately OI. The decision for participants to collaborate and source and share knowledge is motivated by individual reward (such as establishing network or long-lasting contacts), skill acquisition (such as learning or personal growth in decision-making) and a sense of reciprocity and drive for group gain. The authors encourage greater human resource (HR) manager support for relational leadership and the development and use of multicultural skills to promote KSS. Research limitations/implications Despite the value of our findings, this paper is not without limitations. The authors explained that the focus of this study design was on the work activities of the participants and their skill development and not specific projects or organizations. It was outside the scope of this study to examine variations across organizations and individuals as the authors wanted to focus on multicultural skills and relational leadership as enablers for OI. The authors recommend that future studies extend our research by unpacking how various boundary conditions including relational leadership and multicultural skills impact KSS and OI over the life cycle of innovation teams within large multinational organizations, across countries and ethnicities. Practical implications The study's findings provide managers with improved understandings of how to enable an individual's willingness and readiness to source and share knowledge through multicultural skills and relational leadership. Managers need to ensure that human resource management (HRM) practices celebrate multicultural skills and support relational leadership in innovation teams. The authors suggest managers engaged in OI consider the components of social exchange as described by Meeker (1971) and utilize reciprocity, group gain, rationality and status consistency to support the emergence relational leadership and KSS in innovation teams. Originality/value In this paper, the authors contribute to the dearth of literature on the boundary conditions for OI by examining the role of relational leadership and characteristics/skills of the workforce, namely multicultural skills and contribute to the scarce research on the role of employees with multicultural skills and their impact on OI and present multicultural skills/experiences and relational leadership as enablers for OI.
... It must be also taken into consideration that middle manager's perceptions of top manager's leadership and inclusion practices enable the combination of cognitive and motivational dimensions, something so far relatively neglected by the strategy microfoundations approach (Foss & Lindenberg, 2013). Information and knowledge are not properties of organisations (Nelson & Winter, 1982), but rather of the individuals that are parts of them (Felin & Hesterly, 2007). ...
Objective: We used the microfoundations lens to contribute to studies on the interaction between top and middle managers, as well as to studies on the cognitive effets of strategy implementation.Methodology: Empirical evidence result from a survey conducted with 104 middle managers of a large size telecommunications company operating in Brazil.Originality: Making use of traditional and contemporary literature and in opposition to simplified assumptions about managers'interfaces, we revealed the relevance of managerial interactions and their idiosyncratic and inimitable nature.Results: Our analyses revealed that a combination of micro adaptation practices by middle managers and their perceptions regarding top manager's participative leadership positively influenced the way implementation is cognitively realised. Such effects are even more pronounced when the two groups of managers experience a good relationship.Theoretical contributions: The survey, in pointing to microfoundational aspects that contribute to strategy implementation, opens up possibilities for future studies based on this theoretical perspective. It also contributes to the practice, by elucidating aspects, both behavioural and cognitive, susceptible to management and to improvements in the implementation processes.
- Randall E. Westgren
- Peter Foreman
We argue for a new microfoundational approach to organizational identity to replace common vertical theory-borrowing from individual identity theory. Organizational identity becomes either an individualistic account of member representations of the group identity held together by other-regarding cognitive structures or a group-level account where jointly understood identity is tied to joint goals and agency as we-intentionality. Organizational identity is linked to collective action through intentionality. For large organizations, jointly held identity is crucial to guide individual action on
- Mr
- Theuns Pelser
South African mining organisations are facing numerous challenges: decreasing commodity prices, policy uncertainty, rising input costs and increasing stakeholder expectations. In order to successfully address these challenges, each mining organisation needs to respond in a unified, aligned way. This study determined the degree of perceived organisational alignment among managers within South African based mining organisations and uncover the key enablers of organisational alignment. Data was collected from 286 managers from a selection of all the major South African mining commodity sectors on their perceptions of the degree of organisational alignment as well as on the enablers of organisational alignment. Applying structural equation modelling, five of the eleven organisational alignment enabling factors indicated a unique influence of practical importance on perceived organisational alignment. Three data-model fit tests confirmed that the pattern of variances and covariance in the data was consistent with the hypothesised framework of organisational alignment specified in this study. The outcomes and practical value of this study were the following: a conceptual framework of organisational alignment; a validated and reliable measurement instrument of perceived organisational alignment and its enabling factors; and a range of recommendations on how South African mining organisations may improve organisational alignment.
Purpose Prior research has reported the indirect implications of firm's dynamic capabilities on their competitive firm performance. Our attention now turns to open innovation since it has been confirmed to be an influential factor contributing to the superior performance of technological firms. So far there has been little research on assessing the relationship between a firm's dynamic capabilities as an antecedent of the competitive performance of the firm or investigations into the mediating role of open innovation in this relationship. Design/methodology/approach Drawing on the theory of dynamic capabilities, we developed a framework as a way to better understand the role of open innovation, which could then help to better explain the relationship between firms' dynamics capabilities and their competitive firm performance. Based on the empirical data of 465 firms operating in innovative and non-innovative industries, we employed structural equation modelling (SEM) to examine the research hypotheses and the path relationships in the proposed model. Findings The SEM analysis revealed that a firm's dynamic capabilities significantly impact its open innovation performance and that open innovation, consequently, impacts the competitive performance of the firm. Moreover, the results show that the path between dynamic capabilities and competitive firm performance is partially mediated through open innovation. Practical implications The findings provide practical implications and draw managerial attention to the importance of: (1) investing in innovation, (2) engaging customers in the innovation process and (3) maintaining innovation management excellence as significant antecedent factors in increasing competitive firm performance. Originality/value Considering the lack of empirical research in the literature on the links between dynamic capabilities and open innovation, this paper contributes to the dynamic capabilities and open innovation literature by confirming that open innovation not only mediates the relationship between these two aspects but also strengthens the effect the dynamic capabilities have on competitive firm performance. Besides, due to the significant impact of dynamic capabilities on open innovation, dynamic capabilities might be regarded as an antecedent of open innovation.
- Michael C. Jensen
- William H. Meckling
This paper integrates elements from the theory of agency, the theory of property rights and the theory of finance to develop a theory of the ownership structure of the firm. We define the concept of agency costs, show its relationship to the 'separation and control' issue, investigate the nature of the agency costs generated by the existence of debt and outside equity, demonstrate who bears the costs and why, and investigate the Pareto optimality of their existence. We also provide a new definition of the firm, and show how our analysis of the factors influencing the creation and issuance of debt and equity claims is a special case of the supply side of the completeness of markets problem.
- HC Wang
- Jay B. Barney
We argue that the risk associated with the value of a firm's core resources has an impact on employee decisions to make firm-specific investments. independent of the threat of opportunism that might exist in a particular exchange. We further explore mechanisms firms may adopt to mitigate the employee incentive problem stemming from the risk associated with core resource value. These arguments shed new light on resource-based theories of corporate diversification.
- J.Y. Shah
- Ronald S. Friedman
- Arie W Kruglanski
Six studies explore the role of goal shielding in self-regulation:by examining how the activation of focal goals to which the individual is committed inhibits the accessibility, of alternative goals. Consistent evidence was found for such goal shielding, and a number of its moderators were identified: Individuals' level of commitment to the focal goal, their degree of anxiety and depression, their need for cognitive closure, and differences in their goal-related tenacity. Moreover, inhibition of alternative goals was found to be, more pronounced when they serve the same overarching purpose as the focal goal, but lessened when the alternative goals facilitate focal goal attainment. Finally; goal shielding was shown to have beneficial consequences for goal pursuit and attainment.
Posted by: serafinaserafinastortze0272907.blogspot.com
Source: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/256054292_Micro-Foundations_for_Strategy_A_Goal-Framing_Perspective_on_the_Drivers_of_Value_Creation